Skip to content

Category: Economics

Krugman on Scientific Publishing and the Peer Review Process

So now we have rapid-fire exchange via blogs and online working papers — and I think it’s all good. Work circulates even faster than it did then, there are quick exchanges that can advance understanding, and while it’s still hard to break in, connections aren’t as important as they once were and the system is much more open.

But, you say, doesn’t this allow a lot of really bad economics to circulate? Yes, but is it really any worse than it used to be? As I’ve tried to explain, the notion of journals as gatekeepers was largely fictional even 25 years ago. And I have a somewhat jaundiced view of how the whole refereeing/publication system has ever worked; all too often, it seems to act as a way for entrenched doctrines to blockade new ideas, or at least to keep people with new ideas from getting tenure at a good school.

The major problem I see now is the disconnect between promotion and the real nature of intellectual discourse in the Internet age. But the quality of the discussion, it seems to me, is if anything higher than it was in the good old days.

That’s Paul Krugman, in a post commenting on the trend toward open science, which the New York Times discussed earlier this week, and which my colleague Don Taylor blogged about yesterday.

How Much Economics Should You Take in College? (Updated)

Portrait of the Blogger as a Young Man

Chris Blattman had a good post last week about how much economics one should take in college, and which every student should read.

In that post, Chris also compared economics to karate:

[I]ntro to microeconomics is the yellow belt, and intermediate micro is the green at belt. An undergraduate degree in economics is a brown and an MA is arguably the black. And if you want your dojo or jedi master status then get a PhD or go into investment finance.

And of course the ass who runs around looking for a fight is the ideologically left or right jerk who manages to turn a conversation about the weather into a diatribe about free trade.

(In college I was actually just such an ideological ass–I won’t tell you what side of the spectrum but leave you to guess. Glad to say it was just a phase.)

There is indeed such a thing as studying too little economics, or just enough economics to be dangerous. In introductory courses, it is often the case that students are exposed to textbook neoclassical economics — risk and uncertainty, market power, externalities, asymmetric information, transaction costs, etc. are assumed away and relegated to higher-level courses. Or when market failures are not assumed away, little to no time is spent explaining how government intervention can actually bring society closer to efficiency.

The result is that students end up believing the government can rarely do good, and viewing the world through the near fiction of the First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics — a competitive equilibrium is Pareto efficient.

I should know: I, too, was an ideological ass when I was in college. Unlike Chris, however, I cannot hide it — at least not from French speakers. Here is a bunch of links to the editorials I wrote when I was editor of Quartier Libre, the student newspaper of the Université de Montréal.

Thank goodness I ended up taking more economics and learning about the limitations of economic theory.

But what’s someone who does not want to do a PhD to do? What shortcut can one take in order to go from introductory or intermediate micro to understanding the limitations of economics?

For me, the key lies in taking a course that will teach you how economic theory is tested as well as how to assess the credibility of the empirical evidence.

That is why I spend the second week of my development policy and my law, economics, and organization seminars teaching students the basics of linear regression and causality. This is also why I dedicate both seminars to bridging the gap between theory and empirics. This goes a long way toward showing students that although economic theory often gets things right, it also often gets things wrong.

In many universities, such knowledge can be found in upper-level undergraduate courses in development or labor economics. This is particularly true of courses in which students have to read empirical papers rather than relying on a single textbook.

UPDATE: In the comments, Emilia also suggests taking an environmental or resource economics class, since market failures feature quite prominently in those fields.

Insecure Land Rights, Land Tenancy, and Sharecropping

Lac Alaotra, the "Rice Bowl" of Madagascar.

My job-market paper — for nonacademics, that’s the paper I presented when giving recruitment seminars when I was on the job market back in 2006 — is finally published.

From the latest issue of Land Economics:

Most studies of tenurial insecurity focus on its effects on investment. This paper studies the hitherto unexplored relationship between tenurial insecurity and land tenancy contracts. Based on distinct features of formal law and customary rights in Madagascar, this paper augments the canonical model of sharecropping by making the strength of the landlord’s property right increasing in the amount of risk she bears within the contract. Using data on landlords’ subjective perceptions in rural Madagascar, empirical tests support the hypothesis that insecure property rights drive contract choice but offer little support in favor of the canonical risk sharing hypothesis.

After working on this on and off for almost ten years, I am glad to finally see this article in print.