Skip to content

Marc F. Bellemare Posts

Quality vs. Quantity in Publishing

As a result of having served as editor of Food Policy (2015-2019) and the American Journal of Agricultural Economics (2019-2023), I’ve been asked to write a lot of tenure and promotion letters these past ten years. This has given me a chance to reflect on how people can be successful in agricultural economics. Given that, I thought I should uncover some of the hidden curriculum behind how people’s research portfolios are evaluated on the job market, for tenure, for promotion, and so on.

But first, what does “successful” mean? This is where objective criteria come into play, but I can think of several proxies for success.1 First, there is success at the extensive margin: Does someone get tenure? Do they get promoted? Are they considered for endowed chairs or named professorships? Second, there is success at the intensive margin: How many Google Scholar or Web of Science citations does someone have? What is their h-index? What is their salary relative to comparable matches? And then there is stuff like the kind of job offers they get when they go on the market.

“Quantity has a quality all of its own,” a mentor once told me. By that, he was alluding to the fact that while some researchers in our discipline (i.e., agricultural economics) are known for publishing high-quality articles, others are known for publishing a high quantity of articles, and that publishing a high quantity of articles can eventually add up to quality. I wanted to talk about quantity, quality, or even both can be leveraged in terms of having a scholarly impact.

“Applied” Economics?

I have received a lot of positive feedback on my first two posts of the year (see here on how development economics has seemingly become about anything and everything, and see here on whether agricultural economics departments should invest further in international development). People seem to be enjoying the longer-form thoughts I share here about the fields I have worked in and, in the process, about the economics profession more broadly.

My interest in writing these posts goes back to my first year of college, when I took two classes which have profoundly influenced my thinking—one on the philosophy of knowledge, one on the analysis of scientific discourse—when doing a minor in philosophy.

I spent part of last summer working on a forthcoming article with Dan Millimet on Yair Mundlak and the fixed effects estimator. While working on that article, I was reminded of how the Agricultural and Applied Economics Association (AAEA, my professional home) used to be known as the American Agricultural Economics Association (it was known by that name when I attende my first AAEA annual meeting in 2003) and how, before that, it had been known as the American Farm Economics Association.1

Note the change in focus: From farm economics to agricultural economics, and from agricultural economics to agricultural and applied economics.

This emphasis on “applied economics” and whether it remains relevant is the subject of this post.

Agricultural Economics and Development Economics: Does the Former Needs the Latter?

At the end of my last post, I said I was going to write about whether there is still a place for development economics in agricultural economics departments in light of how development economics has changed over the last 20 years to go from a field of economics looking at how market failures constrain economic development to being a “field” of economics about anything and everything, as long as it uses causal inference methods and uses data from a low- or middle-income country, loosely defined.

While you may think this is an inside baseball post about agricultural economics, the first half of this post is about development economics overall, and even the bit about agricultural economics might provide food for thought for people outside of agricultural economics.