Skip to content

Category: Economics

Is Greece the New Argentina?

From an article in n + 1 magazine:

“Argentina entered the new century in straits similar to those of a disquieting number of European counties today. With the peso shackled to the dollar, it had (as Greece, Spain, and the other so-called PIIGS on the periphery of the Eurozone do today) what appeared to be an irremediably overvalued currency sapping the competitiveness of its exports, along with mounting difficulties servicing its debt as tax receipts dwindled in the face of recession. The counsel of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) was naturally for austerity. The Argentines should maintain dollar convertibility—that is, a pricey currency—and trim public expenditure in order to cover interest payments. . . . [Yet] austerity in the face of gigantic indebtedness . . . yielded precisely the devaluation and default it was supposed to prevent. If the Argentine experience is truly as exemplary as the IMF once maintained, the story can’t be a heartening one in light of the turn toward austerity today being undertaken in Europe and threatened in the US.”

I couldn’t find an ungated version of the article, so interested readers may have to spring for the actual issue of n + 1.

I think the comparison is a great one given the similarity between the Argentine riots of 2001 and the Greek riots of 2011: in both cases, some external force — the IMF in the case of Argentina, the European Union in the case of Greece — is imposing austerity measures on a national government, and people respond to the threat of austerity by taking to the streets. This is similar to the way food riots break out in response to the threat of hunger and famine.

Ultimately, I believe this will lead to the end of the Eurozone. The idea of a monetary union is a great one, except for one small detail: cheap talk. Countries can pledge to to respect the Euro convergence criteria in order to join the monetary union, but once they are union members, it becomes very difficult politically to expel them for not respecting said criteria.

In case some readers are interested in knowing more about the political unrest that can take place as a consequence of austerity, the edited volume by Walton and Seddon (1994) on the so-called “IMF riots” of the 1970s, 1980s, and 1990s is a very good place to start. On the Argentinian riots of 2001 specifically, the article by Auyero and Moran (2007) constitutes a great read.

Farm Subsidies and Foreign Aid: Why Fund Both?

From a post I had missed when it was published in February but which deserves to be linked to over and over:

“The USDA routinely disburses $10 billion to $30 billion a year in farm subsisdies. President Obama has allocated $47 billion for the State Department and USAID for the next fiscal year (not including proposed expenditures for Afghanistan, Iraq, and Pakistan).

Why does the U.S. simultaneously fund domestic agricultural subsidies and foreign aid? The policies oppose each other. When it comes to promoting development opportunities for farmers around the globe, one of USAID’s ostensible goals, the left hand of the U.S. binds its right.

Agricultural subsidies primarily benefit corporate farmers, distort world food prices, and nudge us to eat ridiculous amounts of high-fructose corn syrup. But these policies are longstanding, seemingly immutable, and have support on both sides of the political aisle, as Jonathan Rauch elegantly and exhaustively describes in Government’s End.”

For me, the answer to the question in the title probably lies in a combination of the rational ignorance of some voters and in the mistaken belief among politicians that there is such a thing as a free lunch.