Skip to content

Category: Environment

The Sustainability Illusion

I had just finished my Masters in Economics at the Université de Montréal in December 2000 when the Québec Ministry of International Relations announced that it was funding an internship at the International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD), one of the three Rome-based development agencies of the United Nations.

Knowing I was going to start a PhD in agricultural and applied economics the following fall, I applied and eventually got the internship. But one thing that struck me from the beginning — from my initial interview with Ministry of International Relations officials, that is — was the emphasis on “sustainable” development.

Wikipedia defines sustainable development as

a pattern of economic growth in which resource use aims to meet human needs while preserving the environment so that these needs can be met not only in the present, but also for generations to come.

The adoption of sustainable development policies is a laudable goal, but given that we often have a hard time knowing whether specific development interventions actually “work,” I suspect it’s even more difficult to know whether specific development interventions (i) actually work and (ii) preserves the environment.

That Thing Called Causality

Any social scientist worth his or her salt knows how difficult it is to make causal statements, i.e., to test whether a variable D (e.g., some development intervention) causes increases in another variable Y (e.g., welfare).

The difficulty usually arises because of the presence of confounding variables. Some of those confounding variables can be measured, but it is almost always the case that some confounders go unmeasured, which compromises the identification of causal relationships.

To solve the identification problem, social scientists rely on experimental or quasi experimental research designs. That is, setups in which D is assigned randomly or in which some plausibly exogenous source of variation is used to make D as good as random.

Causality Squared

But even with an experimental or quasi experimental design, it can be difficult to identify whether an increase in X at time T causes a change in Y at time T+1. So how do we know whether (i) the same change will be maintained at, say, T+50 (i.e., whether the intervention still works) and (ii) both the increase in X and the change in Y have preserved the environment (i.e., whether it is sustainable).

In other words, it is difficult enough to know whether something works in a cross-section, how are we to know whether it will preserve the environment in the future? How distant of a future should we be considering, exactly? What assumptions should we make about the fundamentally unpredictable future? And how are we to rule out potential the kind of negative feedback that would undermine the environment in other ways?

There are likely many people working in development nowadays who “just know” that the interventions they propose or are working on are sustainable, much like there were many people working in development 10 or 15 years ago who “just knew” that the interventions they proposed or were working on “worked.”

In other words, the identification problem is about a hundred times worse when one starts considering the future, and my hunch is that “sustainable development” is just a buzzword. There is clearly a case for more T in experiments.

Update: Of course, this post says nothing about learning about sustainability from the past. The point of this post was ex ante — not ex post — sustainability.

Ethanol and High Food Prices

It is not often that a stroke of a pen can quickly undo the ravages of nature, but federal regulators now have an opportunity to do just that. Americans’ food budgets will be hit hard by the ongoing Midwestern drought, the worst since 1956. Food bills will rise and many farmers will go bust.

An act of God, right? Well, the drought itself may be, but a human remedy for some of the fallout is at hand — if only the federal authorities would act. By suspending renewable-fuel standards that were unwise from the start, the Environmental Protection Agency could divert vast amounts of corn from inefficient ethanol production back into the food chain, where market forces and common sense dictate it should go.

From an excellent New York Times op-ed by Colin Carter, from the Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics at the UC Davis, and Henry Miller, a senior fellow at Stanford’s Hoover Institution.

Here is a telling series of numbers from the same op-ed:

Remembering Elinor Ostrom

Elinor Ostrom (Source: Wikimedia Commons).

Elinor Ostrom, the first woman to win the Nobel prize for Economics (which she shared with Oliver Williamson), passed away yesterday. She was 78.

The official announcement from Indiana University, where Ostrom spent most of her career, is here.

With Ostrom’s passing, social science lost one of its greats. If you’ve never read anything by Ostrom, you should start with her 1990 book, Governing the Commons. NPR’s Planet Money has a nice writeup:

She was famous for challenging an idea known as the tragedy of the commons — the theory that, in the absence of government intervention, people will inevitably overuse a shared resource.

So, for example, if a village shares a pasture, it’s in the individual interest of each farmer to graze his cattle as much as possible on the pasture even though, in the long run, overgrazing may ruin the pasture for everyone.

“It’s a problem, it’s just not necessarily a tragedy,” Ostrom told us when we spoke to her in 2009. “The problem is that people can overuse [a shared resource], it can be destroyed, and it is a big challenge to figure out how to avoid that.”

But, she said, economists were “wrong to indicate that people were helplessly trapped and the only way out was some external government coming in or dividing it up into chunks and everyone owning their own.”

And here is a lecture by Ostrom, on sustainable development and the tragedy of the commons:

The one anecdote I distinctly remember being told about Ostrom, from one of her coauthors, was that her secret was that she worked all the time, and that it was not uncommon to receive an email from her very early in the morning or very late at night — or both.

In fact, here is proof that Ostrom worked until the very end: an op-ed that carries her name in the byline published the morning of her passing.

I did not know Elinor Ostrom personally, but I have a few friends who did. My condolences to those friends and to those of you who also knew her.

(HT: Lou Brown for the Project Syndicate article; Mike Munger for the video lecture.)