Skip to content

Category: Policy

Speculation and Arbitrage on Food Markets

Matt Collin over at Aid Thoughts has a really good post quoting Tim Worstall about arbitrage on food markets:

“OK, so there’s going to be a future shortage of food. That will mean that in the future some people will die from starvation. This is not a desirable outcome.

So, what do we want to happen? We want to pull those future high food prices into the present. Instead of finding out that we’re short 10 million tonnes of grain in 2012 (or 1 million in 2015, or 100 million, whatever and whenever) we’d like people to be aware of this future food shortage. And getting lots of people to do two things.

1) Among consumers, we want people to substitute away from the foods that will be in short supply. Eat potatoes, or polenta, instead of bread or pasta. Cassava instead of rice. We also want people to be a bit more careful about the food they buy: not waste so much of it. A high price now does this.

2) We want farmers to plant more land, also to farm more intensively so they get a larger crop from each acre they do plant. A bit more weeding, a tad more fertilser, this sort of thing. A high price now makes this happen.

So, we want high prices now to reduce consumption and increase production so that we don’t in fact run out of food in the future.

So that people don’t starve to death, right?”

Unfortunately, one of the commenters on the post linked above, who writes under the name Liam, is completely mistaken about the impact of food price volatility when he writes:

“A key question with speculation has to be its affect on volatility. In terms of food prices, volatility is I think the thing everyone can agree on is bad (since both high and low food prices are good for some people).”

I interpret this as a sign that policy makers and the general public are ready for our findings on food price volatility.

(HT: Ryan Briggs via Twitter.)

Development Policy Quote of the Week

“[I]n the world of development, good intentions can often have negative consequences. Unfortunately, the result of such good works is that many villagers now see volunteers and development workers as little more than easily tapped sources of funding for projects that, if the communities were truly interested, could have been initiated by the villagers themselves. (…) Economic development is a relay that takes place over generations, and no single runner can expect to finish the race. Members of the Peace Corps do the most service where they cheer, but do not lead, local development activities.”

— Robert L. Strauss, former Peace Corps Volunteer in Liberia and former Peace Corps country director in Cameroon, in response to a New Yorker article on Peace Corps volunteer Rajeev Goyal.