My article “Rising Food Prices, Food Price Volatility, and Social Unrest” was finally made available online (click here if you don’t have an institutional subscription and would like an ungated copy identical to the published version) last week by the American Journal of Agricultural Economics, roughly three years after I wrote the first draft of it. Here is the abstract:
Can food prices cause social unrest? Throughout history, riots have frequently broken out, ostensibly as a consequence of high food prices. Using monthly data at the international level, this article studies the impact of food prices – food price levels as well as food price volatility – on social unrest. Because food prices and social unrest are jointly determined, data on natural disasters are used to identify the causal relationship flowing from food price levels to social unrest. Results indicate that for the period 1990–2011, food price increases have led to increases in social unrest, whereas food price volatility has not been associated with increases in social unrest. These results are robust to alternative definitions of social unrest, to using real or nominal prices, to using commodity-specific price indices instead of aggregated price indices, to alternative definitions of the instrumental variable, to alternative definitions of volatility, and to controlling for non-food-related social unrest.
In other words, contrary to the popular opinion, what drives social unrest is the food price level, and not the volatility of food prices. That is, what matters is the mean — not the variance — of the food price distribution, and this is robust to a variety of alternative specifications.*
If you have a good working knowledge of microeconomic theory, this should not be surprising: food price increases directly hurt consumers and benefit producers. Increases in food price volatility, which are analytically equivalent to an increase in food price uncertainty, directly hurt producers (as per Sandmo, 1971), but for consumers, it really isn’t clear what the effect on welfare is. Since riots tend to break out in cities, where the vast majority of people are net consumers of food, it should not be a surprise that what drives social unrest is high rather than volatile food prices.
This is consistent with the micro level results in my 2013 article with Chris Barrett and David Just, where we look at the food price volatility (holding food price levels constant) on the welfare of rural Ethiopian households and find that it is disproportionately wealthier rural households — those households who are much more likely to be net producers of food — who get hurt by food price volatility.
Now, for the enterprising young researchers out there, this suggests an interesting research question: We have a pretty good idea that peasant uprisings are more likely when food prices are low, but is it true that they are more likely when food prices are more uncertain?
*One robustness check that is not in the paper nor the appendix is a specification in which the food price level is interacted with food price volatility, holding each individual component of that interaction constant, both in an OLS and in an IV setting. I checked last week just for fun, and in no case is that interaction term significant at any of the conventional levels. I might write a blog post about this, given that it is important to know whether it is high and volatile food prices that cause food riots, but I doubt anyone would want to publish that null finding…